The Realignment: 394 | Ben Ansell: Why Politics Fails

The Realignment The Realignment 8/8/23 - Episode Page - 58m - PDF Transcript

Marshall here. Welcome back to The Re-alignment.

Today's guest is Ben Ansel, professor of imperative democratic institutions at New

Field College, University of Oxford. He's the author of a recently released book,

Why Politics Fails. I was really interested in speaking with Ben because his academic

work and this book, obviously, is focused on the implicit meta-theme of The Re-alignment

podcast. Why? Considering the rising stakes and potential new coalitions, doesn't the American

Protocol System successfully address, resolve, or form new consensus on any of the big issues

we regularly discuss on this show? Ben's work and this overall conversation is a great starting

point and it'd be helpful and somewhat anti-pessimistic to apply this framework to

every specific issue you care the most about. That said, huge thank you to the Foundation for

American Innovation, for supporting the work of this podcast. Hope you all enjoy this conversation.

Ben Ansel, welcome to The Re-alignment. Thank you so much for having me here.

Your book raises an obvious question. When did politics succeed? You could pick any time,

place, country. Obviously, you are in the UK. You've also spent time in the United States.

When would you say as a period people could look back on politics as a process succeeding?

It's a great question and it's a good cold open as well, I'm not sure, to have

me think about the positive moments. I'm going to answer that in a positive way,

but I'm going to do so in a slightly tragic way because I think the big moments when major reforms

have occurred to the apparatus of government and of public services have been in bad times,

have been either in the United States during the Great Depression. I think your listeners will

have different views about the merits of the new deal and the merits of all the policies created

in them, but some of them have been incredibly long-lived in social security being the most

obvious example of a policy that remains incredibly popular and is now almost 100 years old.

In the United Kingdom, the moment that people always look back on is the transition in 1945

at the end of the Second World War and the creation of the United Kingdom's version

of social security. Some of the repensions increased at that time, but the big kahuna there

was the National Health Service, which was created at the end of the Second World War as well.

We have had these moments of success, but the bad news is to get to those moments of success,

something really bad has had to happen that's made it more possible for pre-existing polarization

to dissolve and for there to be a sense of urgency about getting something done.

That's fascinating because you're getting at the core of the ideological dilemma there because

obviously the two programs or periods you're referring to are periods where you had the

expansion of government, whether it's the NHS or the New Deal program. If you're a conservative

listener, you would say, wait, your definition of politics and success really is a definition

that's focused more on the reform aspect of politics. Wouldn't successful politics be something like

the 1990s? Maybe nothing big gets done, but the economy is growing. We're having stable transitions

of power. I'm curious, what do you think about just a more stable vision of politics working and

maybe things are put to the side and resolved through culture or just basic social economic

interactions as opposed to government expanding? That's a really interesting point. To get big

changes to the architecture of government, which in the middle of the 20th century were about

state expansion, of course, they weren't in the late 1970s, mid-80s, 1990s. There's big

transformations of government have tended to be when bad things have happened. It's an interesting

hypothesis. I haven't thought a great deal about whether the great moments from neoliberalism can

only happen under peace. You could argue that much of the 19th century is developing a free market

architecture during 100 years of broadly interstate peace. Of course, there are lots of

non-peaceful things back in the 19th century, imperialism, the Civil War and so on. I think

there's a fair point to be made. If you were a listener in the center right, big successful

moments of politics look like things like the Reagan tax reform. They look like doing something

where you simplify what the government does, where you broaden the tax base and you cut out a lot of

exceptions. That, I think, was made easier for Reagan by the fact that there was clearly a kind

of ideological shift against what the post-war consensus looked like, but it still wasn't an

easy policy for him to put through because you know who loves complicated tax codes, businesses

and special interests, right? We know it's extremely difficult to get those passed.

So you might be right to say that politics is going to succeed in different ways, of course,

depending on what your priors are about what you want from politics. But the success, I think,

generally comes from figuring out ways of dealing with a lot of special interests at once and

overriding whatever their previous concerns have been. I can give you a good example right now about

what's happening in Brazil. So in Brazil, there's a very, very complicated tax code with lots of

different regional taxes at the state level and then at the federal level. The way they've been

used by Brazilian businesses is largely to minimize their tax exposure by coming up with

complicated tax transfer systems where you minimize your exposure by moving money from

the regional to the federal level. So that is actually being simplified under the current

government. And it's not because Lula won the election, because Lula has almost no dominance

in the Brazilian legislature. It's because eventually there was a coalition large enough

to kill the special interests. And so I think, you know, those who are from a more neoliberal

change perspective are the big ones and they can happen in places with as complicated politics

as Brazil. Yeah, and this is just interesting because I wanted to offer that caution just

because of frustration I tend to have with the broad democracy discourse is oftentimes it's easy

to define democratic success or political success as your specific policy prerogatives

being able to pass or not. And I don't think that's what we're talking about, but if you just kind

of listen between the lines, I do a lot of these interviews that seems to be kind of like the

implicit point being made. So I want to offer that caution, but I think a useful way of understanding

what politics is. And once again, this actually goes to your book is maybe and push back if this

isn't correct, but my takeaway from your book is I would define political failure as the inability

to translate popular will into some form of action. So if it's the 1980s and we are entering the

neoliberal era and there's a clear backlash against the New Deal and the Great Society,

politics succeeded. Whether or not you agree with the policy apparatus of the Reagan administration

because it translated the will, which was translated by the majority's Reagan one in

two presidential campaigns into tax cuts, due regulation, et cetera, et cetera, et cetera.

And in the New Deal, that popular world looked like, hey, we're going to actually impose more

of a state on laissez-faire capitalism. So is that a useful way of understanding what

successful politics could look like then? Yeah, I think it's fair to say that

in a democracy, in a political system where we think self-rule is important, we cannot assume

that self-rule naturally has to benefit one side of the ideological spectrum. And I think

many commentators and many of my colleagues, it's very easy to mistake your views about what

politics should look like and who you would vote for for a successful democratic system.

And so I think we have to be really careful about that. That's been one of the great debates

we've had in this country, the United Kingdom, about the merits of the Brexit vote.

Regardless of one's views about whether this was a good idea or not, a 52 to 48 percent majority

vote is a 52 to 48 percent majority vote. And presumably that reflected a shift in the general

public's attitudes about the European Union from the referendum that brought Britain in in the

first place. If we can't tolerate a country that changes its mind from left to right and back again,

then we're simply not tolerating what it means to self-govern, because the assumption then is

there's a dictatorship of whoever you prefer. So I think your rejoinder is really worth making.

I do think, and I argue very strongly in the book, that that doesn't mean that there's a

simple thing that we should call the will of the people, because that's such a complex thing to

define. It even means complete consensus, in which case we never get anything done. Or it means some

form of majoritarianism. And then we have the problems of losers consent and what you do about

people who are in the minority from election to election, that might be fine. But if you're always

in the minority, right, if you if your side never wins, then that's a challenge for democracies to

figure out how to deal with. And simply claiming that majority rule is the will of the people.

And therefore everybody needs to shut up doesn't assuage the people who always lose, right? And so

that's a challenge for any democracy to deal with. So let's just get to definitions then.

Can you just define what politics is? Sure. It's obvious, but it's also a complicated question.

It is a very difficult question. So what do we mean by politics? We mean

how we make decisions about what we're going to do collectively. And that's a really broad

definition. Let me distinguish that from the law. Because in a way, when we write laws,

and when we interpret and follow laws, we're also doing something along those lines. But when we

interpret and follow laws, we're doing so with a third party that stands behind the law and can

enforce it, right, that can punish us if we don't follow the law and then sets the procedures by

which we have to follow if we want to change or interpret that law differently. Fundamentally,

there's no third party that stands behind politics. Unless one wants to get kind of divine right

about this, there's no third party that we can call on to enforce truly political decisions.

And there's an example I've been using since I wrote the book, which is the deal that we as

voters have with politicians. So I'll give an example from the United Kingdom. In the 2019

general election that Boris Johnson won, he was opposed by the Labour politician Jeremy Corbyn,

who was a socialist. And one of Corbyn's policies was to introduce free broadband for everybody

in the country. Okay, so that's in the manifesto, that's something you could vote for. So imagine

Jeremy Corbyn had one and we're in the world of this counterfactual. And a year later, you're like,

where's my broadband? Where's my free broadband? It didn't happen. What can you do about it? You

can wait till the next election to punish the party for not giving it to you. But there's no one you

can call on in the same way that if you asked ATT for broadband or Comcast for broadband,

and then they didn't deliver, well, you could sue them. And political life is about essentially

these very contingent promises that politicians make to voters, that politicians make to one

another, that countries make to one another, that can't truly be enforced. I'll give you one

final example on this. We talk a lot about the challenge that Ukraine has had not being a member

of NATO. It's always always been on this kind of NATO glide path, or a kind of friend of NATO.

But being a friend of NATO did not compel in any way NATO members to intervene and prevent the

Russian invasion. It didn't compel them to attack Russia. And you might say, bad news for Ukraine,

but good news for Estonia, because Estonia is a NATO member, so we are all obliged to protect

Estonia if it's invaded by Russia. But here's the problem with that. If that had happened under the

Trump administration, and Trump, no great friend of NATO, had seen a Russian invasion of Estonia and

said, hey, too bad, what could Estonia have done? Again, there was no one they could call on, right?

There was no third party that they could call on to arrest Donald Trump for not following

NATO rules of collective security. And that makes political life really difficult. It means that

even a treaty as seemingly strong as NATO ultimately can only be enforced if we want to enforce it,

not by some actor that stands behind it. To me, that's a truly political problem in nature.

And can you talk a little bit about the, because I'm interested in your point around

the difference between law, like the legal code, and then politics. Talk about that side of the

ledger, because I do think when I'm just thinking of conversations I've had with listeners or

of people who have frustration with politics, there's a real lack of, the differences between

these two categories are difficult and often frustrating. So focus on the legal side of things.

Sure. I mean, I'm not an expert on law and politics, so I'll just borrow what my friends

in political science would say about it, which is that what lawyers believe they're doing,

and what politicians believe they're doing, are I think different domains, right? So what lawyers

argue they're doing, and perhaps truly believe they're doing, is John Roberts like, or at least

this is what Robert said, right? I'm going to call them as I see them. I'm behaving as an empire.

There is a rigid code of symbols and rules that are out there that I am simply interpreting

and applying to this particular case. And I'm doing so knowing that I have the 800-pound gorilla

of the United States government standing behind me to enforce, as for example with school desegregation,

to enforce those rules if people don't want them enforced. So that's the kind of idealized take

on the law. I think people's cynicism about the law is natural, because firstly, it's not obvious

that judges are truly neutral umpires, even if they believe themselves to be so, right? We all

come to this world with a set of values that drive how we interpret information. We can claim

to be originalists, but now we've discovered that KBJ has her own form of textual originalism

that's very different from Samolitos. So even then, it's not super clear how one would do that. But

more importantly, judges are appointed by politicians and politicians seek to court curb

all the time, right? So we began by talking about the New Deal, but the New Deal was a moment of

great democratic challenge for the United States in that the Supreme Court tried to overall various

parts of the New Deal and then FDR himself tried to overall the Supreme Court and to potentially

pack it, right? And we had ultimately a deal that saved the Supreme Court, but that suggests the

legal systems themselves are embedded in this core political problem, that they don't have any

backup that they can call on, right? There's no sort of judge of the judges or judge of the political

system that can enforce the way in which courts and politicians interact and to give you a really

up-to-date example of that, look at what's going on in Israel currently with the attempts by the

Netanyahu government to restrict judicial review, which the courts oppose, which members of Mossad

and the IDF oppose, but nonetheless, there's no third party on who they can call to enforce

the Netanyahu behaves, you know, you know, makes judicial legislation in some kind of legal way.

It's not possible. It's ultimately political. So a couple of follow-up questions then. So number

one, if you're someone who's looking at that Jeremy Corbyn alternate universe where he promises

universal broadband in the UK, but he doesn't deliver it, do you or does the political science

field have a grand unified theory of what separate from intent makes politicians actually do something

that they promised? Because I think the key pushback to, let's say, a jilted labor party

voter who's mad at Jeremy Corbyn for not passing universal broadband in the scenarios of a look

like public policy is actually super complicated. And that's like a very, very, very big ask. So

you have to separate the fact that he probably, and I assume like knowing Jeremy Corbyn politics,

he actually meant that he was going to do universal broadband, you have to separate

the difficulty from intent. So what actually, especially in those difficult situations,

forces something into actual implementation or action?

Yeah, I worked in government in the heights of the new labor era. I worked in for the Treasury,

the Britain's Finance Ministry, for two years, 2004 to 2006. And so I now know, as I hope most

local scientists should know, how very, very difficult it is to make policies and to make

policies effective. So one reason why you promise that you tell the general public doesn't happen

is because it's simply not possible. The money runs out in some fashion or you made a mistake

and you acknowledge that. You would hope that the public are forgiving enough to acknowledge

that this can happen. But I also think that it's important for politicians to be constrained by

reality and not to make promises that they can't keep. And so I think the political science answer

to all of these questions is, don't trust the words that come out of democratic politicians'

mouths. They might happen, they might not. Trust not what people say, but your ability to punish

him for it not happening. In other words, trust accountability rather than assume intent or

representation is the way that you get to policies. And so for quite sort of bare-bones,

formal Democrats like me, I mean, I'm not somebody who thinks countries are not democracies unless

they've accomplished a whole set of wonders in terms of political equality and social equality.

I think a democracy is a democracy when you can kick the bums out. When the process by which you

kick the bums out is free and fair, but ultimately what matters is your ability to do so and to do

so time and time again when they don't satisfy you. And that puts me, I guess, on the kind of

we're all fallen angels in the world, right? I don't expect politicians to be able to do what

they say. They do at least want the ability to express my discontent of them. And so to that

extent, I think a lot of the very heated arguments that political scientists made between 2016 and

2020 that the political systems of the United Kingdom and United States had somehow become

undemocratic, I think are fundamentally wrong. And I argued so over social media at the time.

And indeed, we have seen rotation of leaders over that point in time, right? Donald Trump is no

longer president. It's a really tough question to know what would have happened had Trump successfully

overridden the votes in Arizona and Georgia and Wisconsin, right? If Mike Pence hadn't stood up for

the procedure, but he did. And so we're in a world where we did have that turnover.

And that's how our democracies function best, in my view.

You know, it's interesting, as you were giving that answer, I realized that part of the answer to

the dilemma of how do you get politicians to translate their programs to implementation is

the referendum system, which is where the Brexit conversation started. The purpose of a referendum

is, you know, we obviously delegate authority, responsibility to implement and create policy

to politicians. And I don't know the history of referendums in the UK, but if you're looking at

the progressive movements in the early 20th century of the United States, particularly out west,

like I grew up in Oregon, so like Oregon has the system, California has the system,

Wisconsin has the system, you had the referendum to force politicians to do that.

At the same time, though, you know, so I'm obviously sympathetic to the referendum system.

I'm reading a lot about the pre-war era, you know, 1936, 37, 41 U.S., UK. And, you know,

one of the ideas that isolationists on the American left and right had was that, you know,

hey, like we should make intervention in foreign conflict, something that's up to a referendum,

which by definition is a horrible, horrible, horrible, horrible idea on a couple of different

levels. So we could be sympathetic to referendums, but also notice the weaknesses. Like, what do you

think about referendums as a solution to the dilemmas we're discussing today?

I mean, I think you sit down and one quick thing. And the defense of the referendum is if I'm a,

you know, UKIP or Tory, you know, voter in 2014-2015, I would not trust David Cameron's

Conservative Party to actually pass Brexit if he promised it in a pamphlet. So that's

where I understand the need to have a referendum to implement that 52-48 point of view.

Yeah. Yeah. I mean, I think we learned a lot about people's willingness,

so-called Democrats' willingness to go through with a Democratic referendum in the United Kingdom

in 2016. You know, I was somebody who supported the remain site. Obviously, I therefore didn't

want the outcome that happened. But I think it became clear to me and others over this period of

time that coming up with incredibly convoluted ways to justify why you could ignore a referendum was

ultimately anti-democratic. Now, you can then get into these questions about, well, should you have

multiple referendums for the same issue? If it's a complicated one, should you have a supermajority?

And, you know, those are viable arguments to have. But ultimately, if you didn't have them

before the referendum, it's closing the gate after the horse has bolted and coming up, you know,

it's like the old kind of best of three, best of five, best of sadly, way of trying to win a game.

So I think, you know, you have to go through with the system that you encouraged. When people say

things like, well, a majority of the registered voting public did not vote for this. But, you know,

we don't normally count the people who didn't vote in elections. So I think we have to be careful.

That's a choice in and of itself in a weird way. And unfortunate. I think it's unfortunate, but

it's a choice in and of itself. It's a choice in and of itself. And of course, it works really

poorly for the example of Brexit, which had much higher turnout than most general elections had

anyway. So you'd have to sort of throw out every other election on the same principle.

I think referendums are clearly democratic in a majoritarian sense. I think when you get 60,

40 results, which is quite often with, you know, the ballot initiatives, popular ballot initiatives

that occur in places like California and Oregon and Minnesota and Wisconsin and so on,

then I don't think that's particularly complicated for us to deal with. I think the

challenge is emerging to close cases. One is when you have very, very narrow victories,

in which case you have the problem of dealing with the losers. You have losers consent becomes

a problem in two ways. Firstly, the losers have to accept the result. And that clearly took a

while with Brexit for those who voted for Remain to accept this had happened. But also the winners

need to, they're going to be living in the same country as a very similarly sized group of losers

thereafter. So they're going to have to figure out how to implement this policy that doesn't

produce polarization that will be bad for both sides indefinitely. That said, nothing compels

them to do that, right? This is just sort of political advice, not the reality of the fact

that they can often ignore that. So we have a losers' consent problem when we have really

narrow elections. A good example that we often forget about is how close Quebec was to leaving

Canada in the 1990s. That was much tighter than leave's victory in the Brexit referendum.

Quebec remains part of Canada, but it was such a, you know, kind of 1% margin that

it does store up a lot of trouble indefinitely afterwards. It doesn't mean that the problem

is over. So firstly, the narrowness. Secondly, referendums I think are less useful when the

problems are really large. And that's unfortunate because it would be nice to solve all of our big

problems with simple decisions. But the example you give about having a referendum about intervening

in foreign wars is a great example there, right? An incredibly complex question which can't normally

be boiled down to either you always intervene or you never intervene. In other words, it's not

really a binary. Resolving it in a binary fashion just punts the problem. Let's say you decide you

are still going to intervene of how to intervene or punts the problem if you say you're never going

to intervene of, well, you know, what if there are massive demands on you? Are there ways of,

you know, providing lend-lease money and things like that, right? So it's normally never 0-1.

And that's exactly what we ultimately found with Brexit, which is there's lots of ways of not being

in the European Union. You could be like Norway and be very, very similar to being in the European

Union, having free movement of goods and money and people, albeit having slightly different

tariffs. Or you could be like Turkey and have the same tariffs, but none of the other stuff.

Or you could be like Russia and be not part of the European Union at all. Or you could be

like Israel and New Zealand, but a part of the European Union's research program, which hilariously

Britain is not, right? So lots of different ways of leaving. And the problem we got to in the UK

was we made the decision to leave. Yes, but how? And then that wasn't decided. And ultimately,

there were another set of differences there that made it very, very hard for Theresa May,

the Prime Minister at the time, never to come up to any decision. And ultimately that only got

resolved by having another kind of referendum-like act with the general election at the end of the

year with Boris Johnson coming in a kind of steamrollering through his preferred version.

Yeah, I really like your rubric for understanding a successful, we're not even just successful,

just sort of a framework for when a referendum makes sense. So for example, given what you're

saying, a vote in let's say the 1990s to decide whether or not to join the EU, a referendum

in that case would have been simpler at the straightforward because the question is,

do we join or not? And then obviously, there's going to be, are we the Norwegian model? Are we

always different dynamics? That's very clear there too. And then it also goes back to the

problems with the World War II example, because once again, does Lend-Lease constitute intervention?

Does war preparedness increasing? Like, does that constitute usage of it in itself? Like,

where can you deploy the Pacific Fleet if you're going to argue that's going to provoke Japan,

etc. etc. etc. That's a poor example, because the referendum itself doesn't actually address

the questions that matter in the first place. Exactly. You get into a Tolstoy's unhappy

families problem, right? Like, there's one happy family, the EU, it has the same Aki that everybody

has to have. There's lots of unhappy families, lots of ways not being in the EU. But prohibition was,

prohibition was in part decided by referenda at the state level, right? But even that turned

out to be more complex than people thought, right? It wasn't clear at the beginning about what

exactly was the level at which an intoxicating liquor was intoxicating. And I think initially,

in the debates, people thought that weak beer would still be allowed, and it wasn't in the end,

but the way that the law was written. And then repeal was also complicated, because it turned

out not simply to turn everything back to pre-1919, but actually to create this whole

complicated array of different alcohol laws you have across the US states, right?

So even in a case of something like prohibition, it seems like a 0-1. It turned out not to be.

You know, it's interesting. Your articulation of the kind of, do you do a do-over if you're,

you know, doing a Brexit referendum, and eventually the problem of just if you ask

me too many do-overs, you can't have a poll. And once again, like, I'm, over time, I'm going to,

you know, take a few listeners off. I've been less and less favorable towards the Brexit side.

I don't know how I probably, if I'm honest, I probably would have voted remain if I were a UK

citizen, but I think the post-Brexit UK is not in the particularly favorable position.

People who supported it would have favored, but that said, I think it would have been,

I think, politically not great to be eloquent, to kind of just do-over referendums until you

get the right answer. That wouldn't have been democratically legitimate. But you're raising

that point brings to mind a bit of squeamishness I have with democratic reformers. So when we just

try to put the question as clearly as possible or comment, then question. I've spoken with a lot

of folks who favor, hey, like, what's abolished first past the post-voting, or let's have

what's have a system like Alaska where, you know, you do, you know,

man, I'm forgetting all these different terms. This is really embarrassing because I've done

these episodes, but you do the system or like-

Yeah, because single transferable vote and things like that.

Yeah, single transferable vote, all those different systems. I get squeamish about them

because you can make all sorts of arguments in favor of them, but they very clearly are intended

to produce a result. The intended result of most of these reforms. And once again,

I'm moderate in my politics. So obviously, I'm policy sympathetic to this is, hey,

like, let's produce a more moderate result. Let's have open primaries. You don't have,

like, extremists take control of political parties. You got the campaign accordingly,

et cetera, et cetera, et cetera. I'm squeamish, though, because very explicitly or implicitly,

if you're being a little less honest, the result is we want to have specific policy results

emerge in these democratic reforms. What is your thought on that dynamic or that dilemma?

Well, you're absolutely right, right? Every electoral system biases particular outcomes.

And I begin the book, you know, we've talked quite a bit about Brexit. I don't want to bore

your listeners to death on Brexit. But I start with this narrative where a colleague and I,

he's an expert on electoral systems at least, I was along for the ride. We went and we advised a

couple of the politicians who'd taken control during the Brexit process of what's called the

order paper, which is basically the right to pull votes away from the government. This was in

the most chaotic period where the speaker of the House of Commons had essentially seized control.

And we went to them and we talked about different electoral systems that the members of parliament

themselves could use. So this isn't just voters. This is members of parliament to make a decision

about Brexit. And what we realized as we did that is that different systems that we offered

differently favored moderate versus extreme options, right? So to give you kind of obvious

examples of this, the form of the election, sorry, the electoral system of what we call alternative

vote is one where you remove first, you ask everybody to rank options, and then you remove

first the option that the fewest people love. But if you're in a world of extremes where people

even want to leave or remain, that means that the boring middling ones get taken out first.

So maybe you don't want that because you're worried you end up with extremes. But then the

alternate alternative vote, the Coombs system, that takes out the most hated, the one that has

the most bottom rankings first. But then the ones are the most hated are probably the extreme ones,

right? So now the extremists are like, wait a second, I don't want to do that. And even worse,

people can then knowing this, they can lie about their preferences. So if you're an extremist,

you can start lying and say, I actually prevent, you know, I quite like this other extreme

in order to take out the moderate option that you think might win. And I have seen this in

departmental meetings over the years. I've seen this at the British Academy when we vote on new

members, everybody always tries to manipulate voting systems, because they think that the voting

system is going to produce a certain outcome. So when democratic reformers in America talk about,

look, everything would be so much simpler, and more representative of people's breadth and

portfolio of views, if we allow these kind of ranking systems, they forget that a different

ranking systems privilege moderate versus non moderate outcomes. So which ranking system do you

want? And secondly, that people lie when they have ranking systems, and they misrepresent how much

they like things. And mathematically, there is no way of resolving this problem. There is no perfect

electoral system. So all I would say to colleagues in America who think about democratic reform is

say to them, look, the bigger problems seem to me to be ones about malapportionment and

misrepresentativeness in terms of partisan gerrymandering, and arguably in terms of the

structure of the Senate, although no other house in the world is that great. But funnily enough,

if you look at the House of Representatives, which is often a kind of crazy institution in

terms of how it's run, it actually mirrors pretty well the overall vote, right? It's pretty

representative. It's more proportional than we often end up in the United Kingdom, because there's

only two parties playing in the States. So I would say be careful what you wish for with this.

And don't imagine that there's some kind of system that even if you think you could get it,

and it gave you what you wanted, that people wouldn't somehow undermine.

Yeah, and that's a helpful note. By the way, Roy, the phrase that was mentioned to me is

ranked choice voting. That's what I was thinking. And this is where you get into the job of a

politician. I would much rather, and once again, hindsight's 2020, and a lot of these activists

are responding with democratic reforms in this specific period of time, because they've seen

issues raise up. But I think from my perspective, the time to reform America's political system is

during the 1990s. If we're saying bold economic reforms and change could happen in response to

a crisis, I think that political reforms are probably best implemented in an ideal world

when there are not complicated social, cultural questions up for grabs, where the two extremes

in themselves are going to want to push back, because very clearly the reforms are going to

advantage one side of the other. It's probably best to do progressive, giving everything from

women to the right to vote, to changing the way that senators became senators in the 1910s versus

the 1930s. So what's actually getting- I think your point is things are much easier when you have

economic growth. Yes. It is much, much easier to make major political decisions where there are

going to be some losers, where theoretically the winners could pay off the losers. They don't always,

but it's much easier to avoid polarizing outcomes when there's more to go around.

Yeah. Let's actually, speaking of which, let's actually get into the book. What I think is very

helpful is you provide a framework across five different issues where I don't want to misquote

you, but it's not that there's consensus on where we're trying to go, but we want to live

in a society where there's equality. We want solidarity. So just explain these five concepts

that folks can take notes and go from there. Yeah. And so this, in a way, is a challenge of the book,

because some of your listeners might agree with these big five collective goals, but

let's reach them out as broadly as we can. So there are five things I argue that we all want,

democracy and the ability to self-govern. Equality, and this is a bit tricky we can come to in a

second, but let's view it as all be treated equally in some way. Solidarity, which is the idea that

we would all like to be looked after when times are hard and to feel that we looked after others

when times were hard for them to some degree. How we do that, of course, we can come to.

Security, I think fairly uncontentiously, we'd all like to be safe. And prosperity, we'd all

like to have as much as our parents and grandparents had and hopefully more. So those are the sort of

five big goals in the book. And then the motif that runs through the book, sort of the simple answer

to why politics fails, is that every time we try to get to one of those collective goals,

our individual self-interests clash and make it harder for us to achieve that. And that's

something that anyone who's taking classes in political science or economics or sociology

will know about. We often call the collective action problem. There are ways in which each

of our individual interests push against those collective goals and where it's very hard to

stop us from either lying about what we want or cheating, reneging, slow walking, slacking off

and preventing us from getting what we want. And so throughout each chapter of the book,

your readers will find, okay, I get it why my individual interests make it hard to achieve

these collective goals. And what I really want readers to take from this is also to understand

that that's not immoral in any way. That's just sort of natural human behavior. We are all imperfect.

And it's always easier for each of us to see what's in our individual interest and to hold

collective goals at the same time, but not be willing to always make the sacrifices that we

get. So I want to go through these five in a couple of different ways. So one, I'd love to learn

your methodology. We're determining these are the five, which we can broadly say.

Actually, this isn't a leading question. I have a secret follow-up where I'm going to say this

is incorrect. I'm just genuinely curious. How do you come to the belief that these are the five?

Yeah, so that's a great question. In a way, there's an element of the book that is doing for

the field of political economy that kind of splits across economics and political science,

what some other books have done for behavioral economics. So what I'm trying to do is say,

look, these are the big types of questions that social scientists are interested in.

I think they broadly fall into these five categories. Another way to think about it is just

to look at the kinds of questions where you can get 75, 80% of people to support kind of generic

suggestions in polls. So in most public polling, even in the United States, people think the gaps

between rich and poor are too large. Now, do I really believe that most Americans will be willing

to undergo the types of taxation that might make a big difference to that? I don't know.

But I also think when you can get three quarters of Americans saying that the gaps between rich

and poor are too large, that evokes some kind of preference for equality. And I go through this

in the opening chapter about most people think that there should be some guarantees to public

health and public education, that solidarity. I don't know if I have to make the argument too

heavily about wanting to be secure, but certainly around the world, democracy remains incredibly

popular. Ironically, it remains more popular with people who live in dictatorships. But I think that's

a kind of familiarity breeds contempt problem, I guess. The final thing I would say about this is

there's a big one that people ask me about, but not being in here. And in my view, it's in the

equality chapter, but that's liberty. That's freedom. And I think that's after all, liberty,

equality, fraternity. Well, fraternity is solidarity and equality is equality. So where's the liberty?

Well, in part, it's in democracy, right? It's in the right to, at least in a liberal democracy,

to say what you want and vote how you want. But also in the equality chapter, it's about equal

rights, equal civil rights, equal political rights, sure, but also equal property rights,

and equal rights, you know, to pass on your possessions to your children and things like

that are another form of equality. That's just the form of equality that libertarians value,

as opposed to what socialists value. So I suppose sometimes when it looks like I'm making a plea

for equality, I'm being a little bit more cunning than that. I'm actually saying, well,

when libertarians talk about equality, they're not talking about equal outcomes. They're talking

about being treated equally. But we can be treated equally in lots of different ways

that sometimes clash with one another. So I want to understand the individual self-interest

aspect. So let me give you an example from democracy and wonder if this is kind of what

you're suggesting. So a broad majority of this country believes in democracy, broadly construed.

I think there's a case you could make that, for example, the District of Columbia or a territory

like Puerto Rico are not experiencing fully fledged democracy in the sense that, you know,

they're obviously citizens, but they don't have senators. However, from an individual interest

perspective, a clear reality of the District of Columbia and Puerto Rico gaining the vote,

due to the demographic makeup of the states, is that the Democratic Party

would get four additional senators, which would impact all these other different issues.

So there's a tension between the obvious fact, I think if you talk to most people,

and let's put aside, you know, people who get a little technical and say, well, the Constitution

says the District of Columbia is not a state, just let's put those people aside for a second.

We talked to most colloquial people. I have many of those people.

Yes. And guess what? That's not it. And I'm not even being dismissive. That's actually not an insane.

I think the case of Puerto Rico, especially if they wanted statehood,

is much more complicated than the District of Columbia, to be frank. But that said,

if you talk to most people, they would say, yeah, I get it. I get why, you know, it makes

sense for them to be senators. But if, you know, I'm a conservative, I'd say, okay, interesting.

Would you want ex-Supreme Court justice to come about? Because that, and I think very quickly,

from a self-interest perspective, from a conservative, would say, yeah, no,

there's a limit on how, quote, unquote, democratic I would actually want to be in

practice. Is that a way of kind of articulating the dilemma you're talking about?

Yeah. Well, look, I am a firm believer that everybody in politics acts on self-interest,

and rather, we can judge them for that, right? We can judge people

morally on their views about statehood for D.C. or Puerto Rico. But on a self-interested basis,

no one is doing something weird here at least, right? So at least it's explicable.

And for me as a political scientist, I'm interested in explaining behavior rather than

justifying it. And that doesn't mean that there's not a role out there for making moral claims about

politics, but that's just not the role that I'm interested in in this book. I think it's sometimes

just helpful to understand why the world is the way it is, right? So what you're saying is

absolutely right, right? It's not surprising in any way that debates about statehood for the

District of Columbia and Puerto Rico at the same time, in particular, offer nothing for the Republican

Party at all. And there's a reason why state introductions have often been paired or near

paired in the case of, you know, Alaska and Hawaii was a Republican, Democrat split. In the end,

of course, there was no reason to believe, I guess, that it would have to be like that.

After all, Hawaii was the home of the United States Pacific Fleet. So you might have thought it

would be a Republican state. But throughout the history of creating states in the Union,

it's been incredibly political, right? I mean, just think back to the pre-Civil War,

every issue about Kansas and Missouri. So none of this is new in a way, right? It has always been a

fight. What I think is unfortunate is that there's no obvious territory that would kind of be

obviously on the center right that would allow a deal to be struck. And that's what means that we

were only in these situations where the Democrats take the trifecta and hope that Supreme Court

doesn't get involved somehow, that we can talk about statehood for Puerto Rico and D.C. And I'm

sure the next time, well, even now, right, that Republicans have taken the House, that's basically

off the agenda again. And I think that's always going to be the case unless you have

an increase in statehood that at maximum essentially delutes the power of all the

assistant states, but doesn't have a really clear partisan swing. So when should we expect

something to happen? Well, either there's some other entity, Guam, or something that you think

is going to vote Republican, and so you have a way of cutting a deal, or you expect it to happen

under Democratic supermajorities, which it didn't. But I suppose, you know, those are the occasions

we would expect it to. Otherwise, we're going to get into this crazy world of slicing up California

and slicing the Dakotas in half, rather than up in the South. And good luck with that is all I would

have to say. Another one I'd like to get into, and this is where I really just like you to reflect

on this dynamic. The equality section is really interesting because there's a couple of different

ways one could take it, especially in the light of the recent Supreme Court decision

abolishing affirmative action and just kind of reparations debates you're having in the U.S.

right now. So on the one hand, one could say if you're like to the center right to the conservative

side, well, you know, we're advancing equality. We're judging people solely on them as individuals,

we're abolishing racial preferences, et cetera, et cetera, et cetera. If you are on the left,

you are saying, well, actually, we're not being equal at all because like the nature of America's

historical relationship with racism is that like you need to have these preferences or these

sort of programs to like ameliorate deep structural flaws that result in something being unequal.

So, you know, without asking you to like take a specific step in every single,

you know, American cultural issue, how do you just see and you can go there if you want to go

there. But I guess what I'm really asking you is like, how do you see the battle between

different ways of interpreting these goals? I mean, they are absolutely core parts of the

equality trap as I laid out in the book, which is an equal rights and equal outcomes often

undermine each other. I mean, in this particular case, the ending of affirmative action from a

center right perspective looks like more equal treatment by a more equal process or at least

a more impartial process not taking into account any race or ethnic based characteristics.

You know, maybe the Supreme Court will get rid of legacies whose characteristics, I suppose,

if you're a purist in that should be removed of all types, including, you know, who your grandparents

weren't. So, and from the left perspective and center left perspective, it is a, I would argue

it's not so much a failure of the quality of outcomes, although it probably characterizes that,

but they would view it as not a proper view of a quality of opportunity. The view would be that

opportunity is extremely unequally distributed and affirmative action is essentially equalizing

that playing field. Now, I think both of these arguments have merits to them, right? And essentially,

essentially they're irreconcilable with one another, but it's also not possible really for us to

truly adjudicate because they're just different meanings of the word equality. And to give you

an example of that, there is no race based affirmative action in the United Kingdom in our

higher education system. And that's protected in part by our own Equalities Act, which essentially

is our kind of 14th Amendment, if you right, right, like a kind of equal treatment. And so,

under our Equalities Act, we're not allowed to distinguish among applicants for jobs by race,

by gender, or indeed by age. And indeed, the institution I work for, the University of Oxford,

has its own get out clause from that, which means that I'm supposed to retire at age of 70.

It's got an employer justified retirement age in order to break the Equalities Act, right?

So, we have chosen in this country, or our legal system has chosen to look at this in a way that

has been out of this American debate already, again, under the auspices, though, of equality.

And so, everybody means different things. I think the debate about what equity means has

made this even more complex in the States, because equity seems to be a bit of a moving

target in what people mean by it in different conversations. And I think it is a kind of,

it's a battle where everybody's speaking past one another, and I unfortunately don't see a way

really for that to be resolved, because these are just fundamentally different conceptions

of what equality is about. So, I guess the big wrap up question, this is an

unhelpful question to ask a political scientist is, okay, so what's to be done here? This isn't

exactly like that. I think of this more as a framework slash toolkit book, understanding

and diagnosing, but just sort of to kind of push you on it then. Let's say you are in a position

of responsibility, what should one's takeaway be here? Okay, I guess what, so if you're a reader of

the book, there is something I'd like you to get out of it, which is to make peace with the fact

that people disagree on things. I think that's a really important fundamental truth of being human

that our echo chambers in social media often make us, in a way we know that people disagree with us,

we just hate them for disagreeing. And I think I would like to for us to acknowledge that

disagreement is healthy, perhaps not the type of disagreement that we have, but most importantly,

that there isn't a way around it. And what politics does is it provides us with the

institutions that we use to deal with the fact that we disagree. And so the big kind of,

why does politics fail, psych meta answer at the end of the book is, well, it's going to really

fail if we pretend we can get along without it, and we can squeeze it out either with, you know,

through markets or technology or some kind of Elon s wizardry, or by some kind of strong leader who

crushes our differences, essentially, that's not going to work, right? We do disagree.

And so I think what effective politics does then thinking about what the implications are of that,

is it finds ways to channel that disagreement, healthily, and over a medium to long run. So

I think a problem with United Kingdom is, yes, our electoral system, which is first past the post,

and so does tend to leave some people out, by the way, including people who voted for UKIP,

right, who were sort of left out of parliament, despite 10% of the population voting for them.

But the other problem with it is it's really short termist. And I do think that countries

that get into this kind of scorched earth politics that we're having in the UK and the US where

Labour or the Democrats come in for four to eight years and are followed by the conservative

sort of Republicans, that everything is sort of stripped out, removed to Sunday when we start again,

is unhealthy for all of us, right? Most of us make decisions in our lives that last longer than four

to eight years, right, when you get a mortgage, when you're thinking about where you'd like to

buy a house and live with your children, where they were going to go to school,

what your pension is going to look like. And if we tie ourselves and our politicians tie us

to essentially the political equivalent of the quarterly earnings report,

then we're just going to end up with this kind of, with this volatility that I think

has been really unhealthy. I do think when people talk about what the good news about

proportional representation is, is that because it's hard to assemble a coalition,

you have lots of parties that are often in power. And that might mean it's unaccountable and you

think, why are the damn liberals always in power? Or why is the Christian Democrats always in power?

But it does lead to some kind of stability over long run policymaking. And I think that's

what we really lack at the moment. And so why we just encourage people not to want to get rid of

the few institutions that we do have that are kind of long looking like the Federal Reserve,

or even the courts, right, which are supposed to think about longer term decision making and

have a horizon that's beyond simply four years either side. Those types of institutions are

often anti-democratic, but they think they're important for us to be able to attain the kinds

of stability we need for each of us, you and I, to actually make the decisions that are important

in our private and personal lives. You know, you actually helped me think of an actual final

questionnaire, which is a common, I'm obviously intellectually sympathetic to this complaint,

but I also just as a person who just does this for a living, doing experience, this is a problem.

A lot of folks complain that politics has infected everything. Everything is political. I'd

against on this week who was saying, you know, why does abortion have to become political? Like,

why does, you know, why are athletes like kneeling and making like the NFL political and to go to

like the left wing version of this critique? Like, why are conservatives turning Bud Light and

Dylan Mulvaney and targets decision to offer some LGBTQ products political? But just from my

perspective, these are, that's just like an obvious separate from like how one feels with

these issues. Obviously, like that's the place. Like if you're an NFL star, you have one of the

biggest platforms in a society is increasingly decentralized. Obviously, you're going to utilize

that venue to advance your perspective. If you are a conservative who sees yourself not in charge

of cultural institutions, you are going to say, Hey, I'm going to make Bud Light political as a

means of like actually fermenting political backlash. So that's politics. So it seems to me,

once again, like I have a hard time sympathizing with the complaint because it's just, it's just,

it's like someone's describing the way the word is sometimes it rains. Sometimes you wake wake up

with a slight hangover. So just what is your kind of advice or like response to people who feel,

but at the same time, I definitely will recognize things probably were not quite as political.

And let's say a calm, like late 1990s, end of history period. What's your kind of reflection on

this dilemma? So, you know, I think everybody disagrees, right? Like I've already made that

point out. And this is just that sort of pervading other areas. I do think the internet amplifies

our ability to see that disagreement everywhere. But cost, you know, your mind back to the 60s

and 70s, right? Not the 90s for the moment, although I'm sure that there was discontent in

the 1990s. But in the 60s and 70s, you had things like Marlon Brando refusing to take an Oscar,

right? And having a Native American woman go up and receive it on his behalf with John Wayne

scowling in the audience, right? Charlton Heston became the head of the NRA, right? So our

entertainment politics was suffused, sorry, entertainment industry was suffused with politics

throughout most of the late 20th century, right? I mean, think about Hollywood and Blacklist thing

and so on, like Xan, Ronald Reagan. So we've always been like this. I think it is, I think the speed

and velocity of the media that we consume just makes us see ever more of this. And everybody goes

through political cycles, but also cycles of being good guy, bad guy. I mean, look at Lizzo

over the last week, right? Like she's done a kind of 180 and how people feel about her.

Look at Kanye. So the speed with which we're able to see artists who are often some of the most

fundamentally flawed people in society, and that's why we love what they do, but we're able to see all

the different views they have on everything. I think our access to that makes it seem that people

are more politicized than they were in the past. And I'm just not sure that's true, right? And in

accounting of the 60s and 70s in Hollywood, certainly doesn't look like a kind of peaceful

world in which everybody agreed. We can just see it more and also we don't have a distance of time

with us, right? We're always seeing what's most immediate to us and getting wound up about

Bud Light this week when perhaps people were wound up about Chick-fil-A five years ago

and wound up about an alcohol industry throughout most of the 20th century and so on.

Yeah, that's really well stated. Well, Ben, this has been really great. Could you

shout out the book for folks who want to go to the links I have in the show notes to learn more?

Yeah, absolutely. The book's called Why Politics Fails. If anyone's watching on video and I don't

know if they can, I'm showing it, but it came out with Public Affairs back in May. It's available

at all good, bad, and mediocre bookstores, so please do read it. This was fun. Thanks for

joining me on The Realignment. Thank you, Masha.

Machine-generated transcript that may contain inaccuracies.

Subscribe to The Realignment to access our exclusive Q&A episodes and support the show: https://realignment.supercast.com/

REALIGNMENT NEWSLETTER: https://therealignment.substack.com/

PURCHASE BOOKS AT OUR BOOKSHOP: https://bookshop.org/shop/therealignment

Email Us: realignmentpod@gmail.com

Foundation for American Innovation: https://www.thefai.org/posts/lincoln-becomes-fai

Ben Ansell, author of Why Politics Fails and Professor of Comparative Democratic Institutions at Nuffield College, University of Oxford, joins The Realignment. Ben and Marshall discuss why the initial promise of the twenty-first century stagnated into dysfunction and stasis, the role self-interest plays in limiting societies from achieving collective goals in the categories of democracy, equality, solidarity, security, and prosperity, and how and why the political process succeeded during previous eras.